Direct Party and Representative Voting (DPR)

More about voting reform

The Electoral Reform Debate

'The operation of the electoral system is not the sexiest of topics. But like indoor plumbing, you start to notice it when it stops working.' LSE Electionforecast.co.uk blog

A new voting system is central to UK electoral and political reform.
The new system needs to be better than First Past the Post.


We need a better balance between the government, the people, political parties and elected members.

The meaning of Proportional Representation

The term ‘Proportional  Representation’ (PR) can mean different things to different commentators, and there are several different PR systems. This term applies only to a system that counts the votes cast and translates them into votes in the House of Commons such that there is a direct and (near) proportional link between the votes cast for the various political parties in the General Election and the votes those Parliamentary Parties will ‘control’ in the Parliament. The term ‘near’ is necessary because perfect proportionality cannot be achieved, and is not necessarily desirable. Most people agree that a nascent political party needs to reach a certain level of support before it can expect to be represented in Parliament.

‘First Past the Post’ (FPTP) and ‘Alternative Vote’ (AV) systems are not PR systems. Neither is the Single Transferable Vote (STV) system.
You may argue that STV gives near proportional results but firstly, there is no direct proportional link and secondly, in certain circumstances STV is a far from proportional system. For example it would not have produced a near PR result in the last UK General Election.

Some people think PR systems will produce more representative parliaments, meaning that the Parliament will have a more representative makeup in terms of gender, ethnic origin, social background, disability, age, education, wealth, etc. This is not necessarily so since the prime aim of a PR system is proportionality for political parties in terms of parliamentary votes, not the different strands of our society that go to make up the parliament. It may be a by-product of PR but nothing is guaranteed.

If PR is only about ‘party proportionality’, is this enough? Much as some people deride political parties, our system of democracy depends on them and could not function without them. Defenders of the FPTP status quo argue that our democracy depends on the election of local representatives who come together to form a Parliament. This is ingenuous. Voters may not know much about their local MP but even if they do, in a General Election, they are likely to base their voting decision on party and its manifesto (or prospective Prime Minister) rather than the individual constituency candidate. Remember with FPTP you have one vote to vote for Candidate, Party and Manifesto, and Prime Minister.

PR focuses on producing a result that reflects the fair balance of votes for all the different political parties. For this reason PR (as a generalisation) is a demonstrably a fairer, more democratic system of election than the ‘First Past the Post’ or ‘Alternative Vote’ systems.

Fair Votes in Parliament

If the voter is asked on the ballot paper to vote for a party rather than a candidate, it is possible to say how many votes each party should have in the parliament, based on the votes cast for each party across the whole country.
Let’s call these numbers the ‘Fair Votes’.

Can you have ‘Fair Votes’ in a parliament? It depends on the electoral system.

First Past the Post cannot result in ‘Fair Votes’ except by an unlikely accident.

In order to reflect the way the votes were cast, many ‘proportional voting’ (PR) systems try to match the number of MPs to the number of Fair Votes for each party. In each case compromises have to be made. Some compromises are less satisfactory than others.

This is most clearly seen in List PR systems where MPs are ‘elected’ from a party list in proportions as close to the Fair Vote numbers as possible. The compromise is that the voter has little influence on the election of the individual MPs. The Party determines the order of candidates on the list. There are no constituency MPs.

Other ‘hybrid’ systems use a mix of constituency MPs and top up list MPs. This means two types of MPs and two ways that they may be elected. These systems require new larger constituencies than those in use for the current FPTP system.

DPR Voting overcomes these problems.
DPR Voting bypasses these issues by simply sharing out equally the number of Fair Votes for each party amongst their elected constituency MPs – the members of the parliamentary party. The total number of parliamentary votes each party has is still the Fair Votes total. Each MP has a share of these votes equal to every other member of that parliamentary party. No change to constituencies is required.

An advantage of the system is that all MPs are constituency MPs and can be elected based on the merit of the individual rather than their party label.

 
FPTP in a multiparty democracy.

The UK General Election in May 2015 illustrates how the use of FPTP produces surprising results that could be described as unfair, undemocratic, erratic, etc.
.

Election 2015 result
Lab
Con
LibDem
UKIP
Greens
SNP
PC
  Seats
232
331
8
1
1
56

3

  Votes
30.4%
36.9%
7.9%
12.6%
3.8%
4.7%
0.6%

The Conservatives won just 37% of the votes, but they will have 51% of the votes in parliament.
Labour got just over 30% of the vote giving them over 35% of the votes in parliament.

The Lib Dem, UKIP, and Greens combined share was over 25% of the vote but between them they get 10 (less than 2%) of the votes in parliament. Is this appropriate representation for a quarter of the electorate?

The SNP won less than 5% of the vote but get over 56 seats, almost 9% of the votes in parliament. This demonstrates the erratic results that are possible with FPTP.

Yes, the pollsters got it wrong. Nobody predicted these numbers. In a multiparty democracy FPTP is unpredictable. Is this fair, democratic? What do you think?
It matters - not least because democracy needs both Government and Opposition, and the decisions Parliament makes will depend on the balance of these votes.



The Electoral Reform Debate

The debate about electoral reform in the UK has been blighted by speculation about which party would benefit – the speculative answers tend to reflect short term thinking, or even very short term.
The important benefits of Electoral reform are long term.

What do we want to gain from electoral reform? The debate about electoral reform should include firstly attitudes to political parties (in general terms, not the particular parties) and secondly the importance of the individual candidates (again in general terms) and their significance in our democratic system.

Political parties are not currently well regarded, but this is perhaps principally a fall out from our electoral system, which not only picks the winner, but shapes the behaviour of all the parties and politicians – and it is not a constructive influence.
FPTP has also degraded attitudes to Politics and MPs in general, but generally not MPs voters know personally.

In the debate, concerns about the mechanics of the vote should be important – democracy has to be open, transparent and inclusive, so this is right and proper. Ideally voting should be simple and thus inclusive. Counting should be simple and quick. The electoral process needs to be transparent, understood and trusted.

How important is the local contest, and how large or small should the constituency be?
MPs must represent their electorate but should or, perhaps more significantly, can they, as a collective group of individuals, reflect society as a whole in terms of its gender, education, work experience, age, ethnicity, religion, sexuality etc etc.

Should the system be party proportional? The electoral system influences whether or not a party with minority support can rule alone, or whether parties have to join together in coalition. Linked to this is the question of whether or not it is good to have a system that makes a complete change of Government after a five year period more likely.

However all too frequently the debate is partisan and shaped by short term advantage, and as a result FPTP is likely to self destruct, and our politics with it. Now more than ever we need a constructive dialogue on electoral reform.



The Voter's Dilemma


Case 1
I live in a constituency which returns a Conservative (or could be Labour, Liberal, Green, UKIP etc) MP. He is an excellent, independent minded MP who will hold the Conservative Government to account on occasions. He is active with specialist skills on various Parliamentary Committees, and also works hard to look after his constituents.
My preferred party is weak in this area and puts up candidates who are clearly second best to the sitting MP. But I very much prefer their policies, and don't like the Conservative Prime Minister.
Do I vote for the best candidate to be the MP even if it means voting for a party I don't want to win? or do I vote for the party I want and elect a useless MP to replace an excellent one?

DPR Voting offers a solution. I can vote for my preferred party in the Party vote, and also for the sitting MP whom I admire.

Case 2
The local Conservative (or could be Labour, Liberal, Green, UKIP etc) MP has been caught out in a scandal, along with several other MPs. None of them has resigned. The MP is standing again in the General Election for the same seat because he/she is popular and powerful within the local party organisation. I prefer Conservative policies and want a Conservative Government, but I am outraged at the corrupt/sleazy behaviour of this individual.
Do I vote for this politician who I believe to be corrupt? Or do I vote for a party I don't want to win.

With DPR Voting I can vote Conservative in the Party vote, and also for the candidate I judge to be the most honest/hardworking etc.

Case 3
The popular local Conservative (or could be Labour, Liberal, Green, UKIP etc) MP has retired. The Central Party organisation has parachuted in an unknown candidate who has no empathy with the area. The hardworking local party 'candidate in waiting' has been sidelined, but decides to stand as an Independent. I want a Conservative Government but I also want to vote for the hardworking local 'candidate in waiting'.

With DPR Voting I can vote Conservative in the Party vote, and also for the Independent candidate, the hardworking local party 'candidate in waiting'.

 

House of Lords Reform

Why the House of Lords need to be reformed.

Useful links:
House of Lords Reform Draft Bill
Background - Constitution Unit publication.
Briefing Paper by Dr Alan Renwick, Political Studies Association
House of Lords Appointments Commission
House of Lords Library briefings: various
Public Attitudes Towards the House of Lords and House of Lords Reform

Lords Reform Proposal

The Lords could be elected by Closed PR plus list. (Plus is for an independent list.) The elected Lords must be different from the Commons. Constituency or regional representation is via the lower house and not necessary for the Upper House. Independent peers could be elected by having ‘Independent' (for a list of independent candidates) as a voting choice alongside the political parties. The campaigning for a Lords election would be minimised if held concurrently with a General Election. Voting (and counting) should be very simple.

Objective – To make an effective elected second chamber, composed of mature experienced individuals with collective experience of all aspects of British life, whose principal task is to improve legislative bills during their passage through parliament into law, and whose secondary task is to scrutinize the actions of the government and act as a watchdog for the rights of the British people, should the Government or lower house appear to act in such a way as to undermine these rights.

This is best achieved by bringing together experienced politicians put forward by their parties with politically independent but experienced individuals to work together to form a judgment on all matters brought to them by the lower chamber, without undue pressures of formal party political allegiance.
Party patronage should be balanced by a strong independent element, and a 15 year tenure (subject to the rules of the house, rather than party patronage.

Mechanism

This could be achieved much as has already been suggested elsewhere as follows.

The Upper House to be composed of 300 ‘peers'
(phased in by enforced retirement of one third of existing peers at the end of each of three 5 year periods)

Each new peer to be elected for three parliamentary terms

One third of vacancies to be elected at each General Election. ie 100 peers per election
(Assumes fixed term 5 year parliaments)

An independent commission would vet all potential prospective candidates for their suitability regardless of party. Independent candidates could apply directly, or be approached by the Commission. Each party could also nominate candidates. All candidates would declare whether they are a ‘party' or ‘independent' candidate. Each party prepares a party list of candidates. The Independent Commission would undertake this task for the independent candidates.

The process of election (closed party list)

The vetted candidates' credentials would be published and publicised

1 The party and independent candidates' lists would be published in order of preference

2 Voters would have an additional ‘Lords' ballot paper with a single vote to choose a party or ‘Independent' (at the same time as they vote in the General Election). Thus each party would win a percentage of the total vote.

3 Based on 100 vacancies, for each party (and independent group) percentage point, one peer would be elected from its list.

Peers should be paid a salary, and expected to be present for an agreed amount of parliamentary time.
Should a peer resign (or be sacked for misdemeanours or non attendance) there would be no ‘by-elections', there would just be fewer peers until the election process appoints new peers.
The parliament act would stand. The primacy of the House of Commons would be acknowledged during of the formation of the new House of Lords.


PAGE UNDER CONSTRUCTION



What does the House of Lords do?
The Role of the House of Lords:

The role of the House of Lords is to scrutinise and suggest improvements to bills, and to hold the Government to account for its actions. But its powers are limited.

The House of Commons decides who forms the government. The government’s survival depends on support in the Commons, not the House of Lords.
The House of Lords has almost no powers to change the government’s tax and spending plans.
On other legislation, the House of Lords can delay bills by one year, but it cannot block them. The House of Commons can invoke the Parliament Acts to get bills passed



The argument for reform

 


DPR Voting - simple, practical electoral reform


Back to top